Effective Board Leadership: The Art of Doing It Well and the Risks of Getting It Wrong

Ray Garcia is a Partner, Paul DeNicola is a Principal, and Matt DiGuiseppe is a Managing Director at PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP. This post is based on a PwC memorandum, produced in collaboration with Stanford, by Mr. Garcia, Mr. DeNicola, Mr. DiGuiseppe, Mayree Clark, and Linda Reifler.

Exceptional boards don’t happen by accident. They’re driven by leaders — board chairs, lead directors and committee chairs — who combine strategic foresight, emotional intelligence and an unrelenting commitment to the organization’s long-term health. These leaders unite directors into a high-impact team, work towards a shared vision, challenge and coach the CEO in equal measure, refresh talent relentlessly and stay unflappable when crises hit. When leadership falters — signaled by groupthink, a poor relationship with the CEO or underperforming directors — they act fast: commissioning frank evaluations, rotating roles, clarifying responsibilities and, if needed, making a change. Outstanding board leaders treat governance as a living system, adapting structures and processes to match strategy and turning oversight into an engine for value creation. By embracing these principles, board leaders can move from “good enough” to game-changing, steering their companies into the future with confidence and purpose.

READ MORE »

Hohfeld in the Boardroom

Roberto Tallarita is an Assistant Professor of Law at Harvard Law School. This post is based on his recent paper forthcoming in the Yale Journal on Regulation and is part of the Delaware law series; links to other posts in the series are available here.

The Problem with the Traditional Language of Corporate Purpose

Despite decades of debate and thousands of law review articles, no consensus has emerged around the fundamental question of what the corporation’s purpose is or should be. One likely reason for this lack of progress is a disagreement between different views of political economy, which are often tenaciously held. Another reason is that strong empirical evidence in support of this or that theory of corporate purpose is difficult to find. But strong policy disagreement and unpersuasive empirical evidence are ubiquitous in academic disputes, and yet very few disputes have the stubborn persistence and seeming inconclusiveness of the corporate purpose debate. These reasons cannot be the whole story.

In a new paper, forthcoming in the Yale Journal on Regulation, I argue that one of the major problems afflicting the debate is the use of a language that treats “corporate purpose” as a primitive concept rather than shorthand for a complex web of legal relations. Viewed as a primitive concept, corporate purpose becomes a coherent “thing” that can be oriented or re-oriented towards this or that normative goal. In this vein, the traditional characterization of the debate is a clash between two “contested visions”—shareholder primacy vs stakeholder governance. Should corporations “be managed… to maximize shareholder wealth”?  Or should they “prioritize the interests of other stakeholders”?

This traditional way of framing the problem requires that one takes a position about which orientation “corporate purpose” should have, which leads to vague or ambiguous claims. For example, the “rise of shareholder primacy” is commonly said to have occurred in the 1970s or 1980s, yet the idea that corporations must make profits for shareholders appears in law casebooks as early as the end of the nineteenth century.  The concept of “stakeholders” has been borrowed from the management literature, but management scholars have proposed 55 different definitions of this term over four decades. The term “ESG”—despite the explosive growth of funds using this label —lacks definitional coherence. Even the very concept of “corporate purpose,” once used in a technical legal sense, is now increasingly vague and fluid.

The thesis advanced in my paper is that corporate purpose, just like other central concepts in the debate—such as “shareholder primacy” or “stakeholder governance”—is what Karl Llewellyn called a “lump concept,” an overbroad label which obscures its more basic components. The ensuing confusion is vividly illustrated by a curious fact. Under the banner of “stakeholder governance,” we can find both Bernie Sanders, a self-styled democratic socialist, and the Business Roundtable, a powerful business lobby.  Something is amiss.

To have a more meaningful conversation, we need to shift the analysis from these lump concepts to their atomistic components. Beneath the surface of concepts like “purpose,” I argue, there is an interlaced matrix of legal relations. The real disagreement lies in the specific design of this matrix not in the vague holistic properties of the lump concept. But to talk about this legal matrix we need a sharper language—and a common one, so that we can constructively compare, assess, and discuss competing proposals. I argue that the work of Wesley Hohfeld provides the foundations of such a language.

Wesley Hohfeld’s Toolbox

Hohfeld—an early twentieth century legal philosopher well known among legal theorists but obscure to most corporate law scholars—argued that the corporation is a mere fiction and that all legal concepts can be reduced to a few basic relations between individual actors with respect to specific activities. I use his framework to propose a sharper, clearer language to talk about corporate purpose.

Just like Hohfeld showed that the traditional concept of “property”—among others—hides a bundle of different interpersonal legal relations, I hope to show that familiar concepts used in the corporate purpose debate—including the notion of corporate purpose itself—are in fact complex bundles of legal relations among market players and the state. Similarly, just like Hohfeld showed that what we commonly call “rights” and “duties” can only be understood in relation to each other—in other words, that there is no “right” without a correlative “duty” and vice versa—I hope to show that stakeholder-oriented corporate governance cannot rely on entitlements without corresponding disablements, or on disablements without corresponding entitlements.

The Hohfeldian architecture of corporate purpose is adversarial in nature, meaning that the position of each actor can only be understood in contraposition to other actors limiting and constraining the former. This implies that we cannot talk of duties, obligations, purposes, or missions—as in the pervasive rhetoric of corporate purpose—without identifying adversarial rights, powers, and other entitlements that give full meaning and operational efficacy to those concepts.

The Hohfeldian Architecture of Corporate Purpose

Consider a simple business decision: Should the company build a highly polluting plant or a more expensive, greener facility? For Hohfeld, a legal relation is always a relation between two actors with respect to one activity. Therefore, once we identify the activity (building the “green” facility), we must figure out who are the actors sitting at the two ends of a specific relation (an entitlement and a correlative disablement) with respect to that activity.

Framed in these terms, a Hohfeldian model of the business decision to build the “green” plant can take several different forms, as follows:

Model

First Actor

First Incident

Activity

Second Actor

Second Incident

I

CEO

duty

not build the “green” plant

Shareholders

right

privilege

State

no-right

privilege

Stakeholders

no-right

II

CEO

privilege

build the “green” plant

Shareholders

no-right

privilege

State

no-right

privilege

Stakeholders

no-right

III

CEO

duty

build the “green” plant

Shareholders

right

privilege

State

no-right

privilege

Stakeholders

no-right

IV

CEO

privilege

build the “green” plant

Shareholders

no-right

duty

State

right

privilege

Stakeholders

no-right

V

CEO

privilege

build the “green” plant

Shareholders

no-right

privilege

State

no-right

duty

Stakeholders

right

In Model I, shareholders have the right that the corporate decisionmaker shall not build the green plant at the expense of the shareholders and, therefore, the CEO has a correlative duty not to. In Model II, the CEO may choose to build the green plant but have no legal obligation to (Hohfeld calls this entitlement a “privilege.”) In Models III, IV and V, the CEO has a duty to build the green plant, but the actor holding the correlative right is different in each specification: the shareholders in Model III, the state in Model IV, and the interested stakeholders in Model V.

These five models represent concrete configurations of legal relations with respect to a very specific choice between two incompatible options—building a green plant or a more polluting plant—of which one is better for stakeholders and the other is better for shareholders. A very tempting analogical move is to generalize from these specific relations to fundamental conceptions of corporate purpose.

Indeed, the main theories of corporate purpose that are often discussed in the literature bear a very strong resemblance to these five permutations. Model I, for example, correspond to a hard version of shareholder value maximization, in which managers have an actual Hohfeldian duty to choose the value-maximizing option. Model II would be a permissive theory of managerial discretion, in which managers may choose the stakeholder-favoring option but do not have to. And so forth.

However, in real-world corporate decision-making, we find different types of relations—whether Model I, or Model IV, or Model II—in different types of situations. None of these relations, however, imply a general principle of the same form. As I try to demonstrate in the paper, there is not, and there could not practically be, a general Hohfeldian duty to always choose the value-maximizing option or the socially responsible option.

Any realistic model of corporate decision-making must take the form of a broad sphere of managerial privilege constrained by adversarial legal relations—rights and powers of shareholders, stakeholders, and the state that limit and shape how managers use their legal privilege. Therefore, the crux of the problem is not in the abstract commitment to shareholders or stakeholders, but in the concrete scope of managerial privilege, and how it is constrained by adversarial legal relations.

Proposals for corporate purpose reform cannot be as simple as a “re-orientation” of purpose from one goal to another.  Instead, they must be detailed and explicit specifications of which new or different legal relations should be established, between which actors, and based on what assumptions about the reasons and motives of corporate actors.

Reframing the Corporate Purpose Debate

Rereading the history of the corporate purpose debate through the lens of Hohfeld’s scheme reveals a major fault line since the 1930s: not the abstract contraposition between shareholderism and stakeholderism, but one between models seeking to expand managers’ privilege and models seeking to restrict it. Interestingly, whether someone proposes an expansion or restriction of managerial privilege often depends on underlying assumptions on the benevolence of corporate actors.

Merrick Dodd, for example, influenced by Louis Brandeis, thought that corporate managers believed in social responsibility and therefore an expansion of managerial privilege would lead to better social outcomes. Thirty years later, Milton Friedman shared the same assumptions on the sociology of managerial power, but given his very different policy preferences (Dodd was a New Deal corporatist, Friedman a free-market libertarian) Friedman drew the opposite conclusion—that managerial privilege should be restricted by value-maximizing duties.

Today, many influential “stakeholder governance” proposals rely on a similar bet—often understated or unspoken—on the benevolence of corporate actors. The bet, however, is quite risky, because it calls for an expansion of corporate power in the hope that it will be used to the benefit of society. If we take the adversarial nature of Hohfeld’s scheme seriously we should be very cautious about taking this bet.

An alternative principle for policymakers or corporate planners wishing to redesign the architecture of corporate purpose in a more stakeholder-oriented manner is instead the following: expand managerial privilege only when the benevolence of the relevant corporate actors is verifiable; otherwise, pair privilege with enforceable duties or countervailing powers.

You can read the current draft of the paper here.

Executive Apologies: Risk, Opportunity, or Relic?

Rosie Miller is an Associate, Jemima McCrystal is a Senior Consultant, and Dominic Reynolds is a Partner at Kekst CNC. This post is based on their Kekst memorandum.

C-suite blunders are everywhere. With growing pressure on executives to be visible, and social media watchdogs noting every word, slip-ups can feel inevitable.

What’s more, leaders are contending with new kinds of reputational challenges. In the UK, a series of high-profile cyber attacks has dominated headlines – most recently the Stellantis breach. Meanwhile, in the US, political pressures are redefining the boundaries of appropriate behavior. Just ask Jimmy Kimmel, who was briefly suspended after backlash to his on-air remarks about conservative activist Charlie Kirk.

For years, the crisis-management playbook was straightforward: act swiftly, apologize to those affected, acknowledge the impact, and outline a response. In 2025, however, that formula is starting to fray.

A growing number of CEOs now refuse to apologize at all. So is the art of the executive apology changing?

READ MORE »

ESG Shareholder Resolutions: Signal Failure?

Lindsey Stewart is the Director of Investment Stewardship Research at Morningstar, Inc. This post is based on his Morningstar report.

Key Observations

  • After new Securities and Exchange Commission guidance on environmental, social, and governance shareholder resolutions, the number of voted proposals fell 22% in the 2025 proxy year.
  • However, average support for conventional ESG resolutions (excluding those by “anti-ESG” filers) has held steady for three years at around 26%–27%.
  • The gap in voting support between governance and E&S proposals grew further. Average support for conventional governance proposals stood at 35% in the 2025 proxy year (36% in 2024), compared with 16% for conventional E&S proposals (20% in 2024).
  • Despite new SEC curbs, poorly supported resolutions are taking up more space than ever. The proportion of E&S resolutions with less than 5% support has increased from 8% to 27% in five years.
  • E&S proposals addressing topics that a significant proportion of shareholders view as material are becoming a rarity. There were only 30 significant E&S resolutions in the 2025 proxy year, compared with over 100 in each of the previous five years.
  • In our view, these trends mean the market is losing useful signals on sustainability factors that are important to long-term investment decisions.
  • The wide gap in voting support between US and European asset managers for significant E&S resolutions narrowed slightly in 2025.
  • Average support for significant E&S resolutions for six large US asset managers (BlackRock, Dimensional, Invesco, J.P. Morgan, State Street, and Vanguard) was 18% in the 2025 proxy year, compared with 17% in 2024 and a peak of 46% in 2021.
  • The same average in 2025 for six large European asset managers (Amundi, Fidelity International, Legal & General, NBIM, Schroders, and UBS) was 91%, having remained fairly stable over the prior five years.

READ MORE »

Merger Remedies Unbound

Dhruv Aggarwal is an Assistant Professor of Law at Northwestern Pritzker School of Law, Albert H. Choi is the Paul G. Kauper Professor of Law at the University of Michigan, and Geeyoung Min is an Associate Professor of Law at Michigan State University College of Law. This post is based on their recent paper and is part of the Delaware law series; links to other posts in the series are available here.

How should foundational contract law doctrines apply to corporate mergers? In a forthcoming paper, we argue that recent changes in Delaware law grant parties an unprecedented degree of contractual freedom to define their preferred remedies in merger agreements, far beyond the limits imposed by traditional contract law. Delaware’s newly permissive attitude toward contractual remedies in mergers stems from a legal dispute about “lost premium” provisions, which allow target companies to recover the premium that their shareholders were promised, in case the buyer breached the agreement and the merger failed to close. In Crispo v. Musk, the Delaware Chancery Court held that Twitter could not enforce the lost premium provision in its merger agreement with Elon Musk after Musk attempted to walk away from the transaction. The Crispo court based its decision on contract law’s anti-penalty doctrine. Under this doctrine, liquidated damages—the contractually stipulated sums intended to compensate the injured party—must not be unreasonably large. The decision came as a surprise to many practitioners, and raised concerns that buyers could opportunistically walk away from deals without compensating the target.  Several months later, the Delaware legislature responded to these concerns and amended the Delaware corporate statute, expressly overriding the Chancery Court’s Crispo ruling and allowing targets to collect the lost premium when such a provision is stipulated in a merger agreement, as was the case in the Twitter deal.

The Delaware legislature’s endorsement of lost premium provisions, despite concerns over their compatibility with the anti-penalty doctrine, is consistent with a parallel, longer-running trend in Delaware jurisprudence: an increasingly contractarian approach to specific performance.  Traditionally, courts have exercised substantial discretion over determining whether an injured party is entitled to specific performance as a remedy, regardless of whether an agreement expressly provides for it. Recently, however, Delaware courts have grown far more willing to enforce specific performance provisions in merger agreements as written.

The legislative response to Crispo and the Delaware courts’ growing deference to negotiated specific performance provisions, taken together, signal a broader shift toward allowing contracting parties wide-ranging freedom to dictate their preferred remedy with minimal judicial interference. But this increasing deference to party-drafted remedies raises crucial questions about the appropriate boundaries of contractual freedom. To what extent should the parties’ stipulated remedy in a merger agreement be enforced as written? How should courts and legislatures balance deference to private ordering with the equitable principles that traditionally govern the enforcement of remedies? More fundamentally, what remedy should a disappointed party be entitled to when a merger falls apart? READ MORE »

Shareholder Proposal No-Action Requests in the 2025 Proxy Season

Marc S. Gerber is a Partner, and Jeongu Gim is an Associate at Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom LLP. This post is based on their Skadden memorandum.

Key Points

  • Corporations submitted approximately 35% more no-action requests to the SEC this proxy season to exclude shareholder proposals from their proxy statements, and about 70% of requests were granted.
  • The increased success rates in 2024 and 2025 and new staff guidance this year indicate a greater receptiveness to grant no-action requests, but determinations remain highly fact-specific.
  • In future proxy seasons, companies should take into account the new staff guidance and the increased success rates for no-action requests based on substantial implementation, economic relevance or that the proposal was false and misleading.

READ MORE »

How a Stewardship Lens May Help Sort Corporate Leaders from Laggards

Luke Pryor is a Portfolio Manager, Kathleen Dumes is a Senior Investment Strategist, and Erin Bigley is the Chief Responsibility Officer at AllianceBernstein. This post is based on their AllianceBernstein memorandum.

Water scarcity, supply-chain risk and board-level decisions underscore the importance of a stewardship lens.

Companies today face intensifying pressures—from surging electricity demand and water shortages, to shifting policies and regulations, to a rise in megamergers. How companies handle these pressures matters to their bottom lines—and to shareholder value. The challenge for investors is determining which businesses will adapt and thrive, and which will struggle. In our view, applying a stewardship lens can help.

That means assessing how companies manage the fundamentals that drive long-term value: resource use, supply chain practices and governance. We believe that companies that conserve water and energy, demonstrate sophistication around their supply chains and maintain corporate discipline are better positioned to protect margins and preserve capital. That discipline can translate, in our analysis, into more resilient earnings and stronger shareholder outcomes over time.

READ MORE »

The New Political Economy of Delaware Corporate Lawmaking

Marcel Kahan is the George T. Lowy Professor of Law, and Edward B. Rock is the Martin Lipton Professor of Law at New York University School of Law. This post is based on their recent paper and is part of the Delaware law series; links to other posts in the series are available here.

Fifty years ago, former SEC chair William Cary famously attacked  Delaware’s role in promulgating national corporate law and argued that to improve our national corporate law, “[t]he first step is to escape from the present predicament in which a pygmy among the 50 states prescribes, interprets, and indeed denigrates national corporate policy as an incentive to encourage incorporation within its borders thereby increasing its revenue.”  Cary’s attack has been echoed in the intervening years whenever a crisis has struck.

Traditionally, Delaware defended its role in corporate law by having its high quality, specialized courts oversee its development.  Legislative interventions have been largely technical and interstitial. Any amendments were drafted by an apolitical Corporation Law Council, with the legislature and political interests playing no material role. Leading Delaware lawyers served on the Council, its deliberations were confidential, and proposed amendments did not interfere with pending litigation. In the relatively rare cases when amendments were controversial, the Council moved deliberately, obtained input from affected constituencies over a prolonged period of time, and developed a measured proposal that balanced the competing interests. Importantly, Council members were able to “put on their Delaware hat” and to prioritize Delaware’s long-term interests, or at least the long-term interests of Delaware lawyers as a group, over the immediate (and often pressing) interests of clients and their out-of-state law firms.

The traditional process effectively responded to Delaware’s democratic legitimacy deficit by cloaking corporate law in apolitical, technocratic expertise: law was made largely by expert judges, while legislative amendments were drawn up by expert lawyers and largely confined to technical issues and the few controversial amendments went through significant vetting and were balanced in substance.  Under this traditional approach, it mattered little that the judges were Delaware judges or that the lawyers were Delaware lawyers. READ MORE »

Could Stock Options Make a Comeback?

Michael J. Kenney is a Principal, and Erin Bass-Goldberg is a Managing Director at FW Cook. This post is based on their FW Cook memorandum.

Introduction

Love them or hate them, everyone has a point of view on stock options.  Some people credit them for driving a growth culture, while others blame them for promoting undue risk-taking in corporate America.  Given evolving shareholder perspectives on performance-based pay and volatile market conditions, it begs the question: could stock options make a comeback?

Since 1973, FW Cook has been reporting on top officer long-term incentive (LTI) trends among the 250 largest companies as measured by market capitalization.  The 2007 and 2008 FW Cook Top 250 Long-Term Incentive Reports described the reallocation of long-term incentives from stock options as the sole LTI vehicle to a portfolio approach of stock options and full-value shares (performance shares or restricted stock1).  The primary driver of the change was the implementation of Accounting Standards Codification (ASC) Topic 718 (formerly known as FAS 123R), which resulted in a charge to earnings for granting stock options and a greater focus on controlling potential shareholder dilution.  A few years later, the 2011 FW Cook Top 250 Long-Term Incentive Report marked the first time in the history of the report that the prevalence of performance shares was higher than stock options, reflecting the advent of Say on Pay and the increased influence of proxy advisors, such as Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS) and Glass Lewis.  Neither ISS nor Glass Lewis credits time-based stock options as performance-based, so companies implemented performance shares at higher rates to receive credit for performance-based LTI programs and bolster the likelihood of a “For” vote recommendation on Say on Pay from the proxy advisors.

READ MORE »

The End of Quarterly Reporting in the United States?

Matthew E. Kaplan, Paul Rodel, and Steven J. Slutzky are Partners at Debevoise & Plimpton LLP. This post is based on a Debevoise memorandum by Mr. Kaplan, Mr. Rodel, Mr. Slutzky, Eric Juergens, Benjamin Pedersen, and Jonathan Tuttle.

Key Takeaways:

  • SEC Chairman Paul Atkins has announced support of a shift from the current quarterly reporting regime to semiannual reporting for U.S. public companies, in line with other jurisdictions such as the United Kingdom and European Union.
  • A move from quarterly to semiannual reporting would have numerous potential implications, including, among others, an emphasis on long-term focus, a reduction in regulation and a decrease in information available to investors.

READ MORE »

Page 1 of 1257
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 1,257