Preventing the Next Financial Crisis

Ivo Welch is Professor of Economics and Finance at Brown University.

We have weathered the worst of the financial crisis of 2008-9. Time for renewed optimism? Unfortunately not. The next financial crisis is already programmed. It’s somewhat like an earthquake in Southern California. We cannot predict exactly when it will happen, but we know that it will. Yet unlike earthquakes, financial crises are man-made. They need not happen. They happen because we allow them to happen. We could take many measures to reduce their frequency and depths, but we fail to do so.

What about Dodd-Frank? Won’t it help? To its credit, it contains many good ideas. For example,

  • Financial firms with access to the Fed should not be allowed to speculate. (The “Volcker Rule” prohibits proprietary trading.)
  • Financial firms that are too big to fail should be broken up by the financial risk council.
  • Financial firms should have higher capital requirements.
  • Compensation of executives in financial firms should be subject to claw back.
  • Whistle blowers can collect bounties for turning in executives if the executives’ compensation was based on inaccurate accounting.

Some good ideas, like an industry rescue fund, died along the way. Other good ideas have been put forth in academic discussions and been by-and-large ignored. For example, there is the suggestion that financial firms should be primarily equity-funded instead of debt-funded, that deposit insurance premia should be risk based, and that firms should disclose much more information about their bets publicly on a daily basis (which all large financial firms already have readily available), so that traders can become aware of systemic correlations in bets.

However, there are two critical problems with all these reforms and ideas. First, meaningful reforms will never happen. This even applies to the provisions already in Dodd-Frank. They will be castrated long before they are implemented. Wall Street simply has too much influence in Washington to allow any meaningful reform. More likely, Dodd-Frank will end up just as another Full Employment Act of Financial Lobbyists (a phrase coined by Barth, Caprio, Levine) and a source of rich campaign donations for influential politicians. As a whole, Washington is corrupt. This is not necessarily because individual politicians are corrupt, but because politicians that are well-funded by lobbyists tend to win elections.

I would be shocked if the Volcker Rule actually came to be implemented and forced Goldman and others out of the proprietary trading business. (Can Goldman simply declare itself to be “private equity” to qualify for an exemption?) I would be shocked if the financial risk council were to break up firms that are too big to fail. (Under what scenario are Bank of America, JP Morgan Case, Citigroup, Wells Fargo, Goldman, and Morgan-Stanley not already too big to fail?) I would be shocked if the banks cannot get around higher capital requirements, maybe not on day one, but slowly over the years. I would be shocked if Wall Street did not find new ways to insure executives’ and traders’ compensation against claw back. (How much of the current torrent in trader compensation [incl. pensions] can really be clawed back in 5-10 years?)

Second, even if I am wrong and tough Dodd-Frank reforms with teeth are actually implemented, none of them addresses the root of the problem. Every single diagnosis (and thus every remedy plan), both in academia and outside, has missed the central and trivially simple point. The root of the problem is that everyone on Wall Street has the incentive to gamble, regardless of whether it is in society’s interest or not. This is not just the case at the top, where executives earn money for risk-taking, but also the case for the traders. Traders earn more money if they take more risk, less money if they take less risk. The root of the problem is really this simple.

We can disagree about how good or bad these gambles are. We can disagree about whether these gambles are ultimately in the interests of shareholders or not. And, if a reader is among the truly faithful, (s)he can even argue that permitting unlimited gambling happens to be in the interest of the overall economy. But there should be no arguing that it is in the interest of gamblers, who are paid if they win, to gamble, regardless of whether it is or is not in the interest of the economy. In the language of economics, this is an externality.

Our current economic regulations are not only neutral but outright perverse. If there is a bet that has a positive expected wealth effect on the equity in exchange for a chance of crashing the bank and with it the economy, then it is the fiduciary duty of executives to take this bet. It maximizes shareholder wealth. This duty increases even more if failed banks might be rescued by the government. (One way to accomplish high risk and raise systemic risk is for banks to lend one another 95% of their gambling capital. A lends B 95%, and B lends A 95%. If one goes bust, so will the other, and the system will collapse, forcing government intervention.)

The bet itself probably won’t be mortgages next time. It will be something else. Maybe emerging-market investments. Maybe a new financial derivative. Maybe something else, altogether. The next bet will be discovered by some enterprising traders and supported by management. It will make many of these individuals fabulously wealthy. It will last for a while, crescendo, and then crash the system. And the rest of us will end up paying, one way or the other. If we bail out the financial sector again, then we pay directly. If we do not, then we will have an economic depression, the likes of which we have not seen in a century. But, either way, we will pay.

It’s already beginning. Wall Street value-at-risk and compensation of traders are returning to stratospheric levels, sometimes even exceeding pre-crisis levels. Bankers are extolling the virtues of ROE maximization–which just so happens to reward higher leverage and more risk. They just can’t help themselves. There is just too much money involved.

It is easy to blame the individuals involved. After all, ultimately, one simple fact is enough to explain the root cause of the financial crisis: not a single perpetrator of the financial crisis is destitute today. Most have become fabulously rich. This includes such luminaries as the former executives of Bear Stearns, Lehman, Merrill, Fannie, Freddie, AIG, and legions of their financial traders and deal-makers. This fact alone is enough to understand why the financial crisis has happened. Economics works! If agents are rewarded for an activity, then there will be more of it. If agents are rewarded with billions of dollars, then there will be a lot more of it.

Did the executives and traders get rich because they had such great talents? Unlikely. Although it is true that some of them may have shifted the odds a little towards the right, the ultimate cause of their riches was the variance and not the mean of the bets. These individuals became rich because of the very same bets that, when they finally failed, caused the collapse of their firms and of our financial system. Yes, these individuals were hurt by the ultimate collapse. They would have ended up even richer if the gambles had paid off longer (and, with high the firms’ leverage, very handsomely so). But, with gambling as their main capabilities, they would have had nothing without gambling in the first place. And quitting at the right time in a doubling-up strategy is tough.

Andrei Shleifer has argued that these individuals believed in their gambles. This is probably true. But I disagree with him that this is the root cause. In my opinion, these beliefs are an inevitable outcome of the system. Over time, it’s the risk-takers that are winning gambles that rise to the top of financial firms. Gambles that pay off frequently and are highly levered but that have a small probability of catastrophe are particularly well-suited to escape all alarm signs. It is traders who took such gambles and won that will run their departments and ultimately the whole firm. Of course, they will tend to believe that their bets had low risk. Any cautious executive who had correctly believed that mortgages were too risky in 2004 would have been fired well before 2007. It was no accident that ex-traders were in charge in many Wall Street firms. It was natural selection.

What can society do? Ultimately, there is only one real cure. We need to reduce the risk-taking incentives on Wall Street. Importantly, limiting the general incentives is different from limiting the specifics of what firms can do. The financial firms have smart employees. If regulation goes into details with what is allowed and what is not, then the executives and lawyers in these firms (earning multimillion dollar salaries) will run circles around the regulators (earning $100,000/year, and hoping to be hired by these firms afterwards; most presidents of the Fed of NY have gone to work for Wall Street after their term was over). Sooner or later, some politicians and regulators that are supported by Wall Street will end up in charge, and they will defang existing regulations. (And it is sooner, rather than later. The nomination of Peter Diamond, a Nobel-prize winning economist, to the Fed Board has just been successfully blocked by Congress, partly for “lack of industry experience.” If this becomes a requirement, then the banking sector itself would primarily control banking regulation, a sure recipe for ineffective and self-serving regulation.) Asking the government to regulate details is like asking a narcoleptic to guard the store–no matter how well intended, it is ultimately hopeless.

It is my belief that if we do not attack the weed by the root, for every leaf that we cut, three new leaves will grow elsewhere. We need remedies that 1) are not easy to tinker with, once enacted, and 2) truly threaten the essential livelihood of the individuals (and not just the shareholders) when the firm takes on large risks.

If these are two important criteria, then there are different kinds of remedies that suggest themselves:

We should legislate that all financial firm employees have a fiduciary responsibility not only to maximize shareholder wealth, but also to control firm risk. In addition, they should have a fiduciary responsibility to the integrity of the financial system overall. Clearly, this will only matter for very large firms, as small firms cannot endanger it.

We should legislate that even if a firm goes bankrupt ten years later, we can recover all compensation (or better yet, all wealth) of the responsible individuals. This should apply to funds transferred to family and friends, too.

We should impose civil personal liability that is explicitly not allowed to be insurable. (We should however allow firms to cover legal defense costs–this is a matter of due process.) Right now, corporate failure punishes disproportionally the public shareholders, most of whom have no real ability to influence the decision-making of these firms. It was not the Lehman shareholders that ran Lehman into the ground–it was Fuld, his lieutenants, and his board. For the future, it needs to be the executives and “their” boards that need to be punished, not the shareholders.

We should weaken the business judgment rule that shelter the board and executives from “willful ignorance” liability.

However, my two criteria suggest an even more radical remedy. We should legislate criminal penalties on the board, executives, and traders for taking on risk, or allowing risk to be taken on, that endangers the firm and/or the financial system. The offense and penalty are easy to understand and difficult to circumvent. Prosecutors are more difficult to lobby and influence than regulators. Criminal liability of individuals in charge hurts exactly where it is supposed to hurt.

The end outcome should be that individuals who are responsible for and/or fail to prevent systemically important financial firms from going bust would indeed go to prison if their firms go bust. If the firm fails or needs to be bailed out, it is prima-facie evidence that a firm had taken on too much risk. Analogous to drunk driving, the crime is not failing (causing an accident). The crime is getting into a situation in which failure can happen (driving drunk).

Is it unfair? I would argue that it is no more unfair than criminalizing other voluntary choices. Why is endangering our economic system not like criminal reckless endangerment or involuntary manslaughter? Why can’t we incarcerate individuals for taking on risks that are so excessive that they can bring down our whole economic system–and, worse, where taking on these risks would just have happened to make these individuals rich if they had worked? There are gray lines–what exactly is reckless and what is not? But this is also the case for non-financial reckless endangerment. The penalties could be proportional to the damages involved. Small bank, a misdemeanor. Large bank, a felony.

Won’t it be too expensive to prosecute? Only if we do not legislate corporate failure as prima-facie evidence of excessive risk-taking. (Again, the crime is not failing; it is allowing excessive risk.) Won’t it induce some managers to try to cover up until the situation ends up even worse, instead of fessing up earlier? Yes, but this is the case for any sanction.

Won’t it hurt the industry? Won’t it discourage attracting “the best” to Wall Street? Won’t it cost us in less financial innovation? Won’t some executives not wander off to other countries? Yes. Some smart people will leave the largest banks and funds, not willing to take the risks. But it’s not as if these smart people will sit around unemployed. There are plenty of other great ways to deploy their brains. They could work for smaller, less systematically important hedge funds and/or more heavily equity-financed funds. Heck, what if engineers started preferring engineering firms again instead of Wall Street?

But I doubt too many individuals will be leave. The rewards will still be very rich, even with five times the equity cushion that firms have today. Conservative, diversified, less-levered, smart lending and investing practices can carry very little risk. With more public disclosure, banks could become more cognizant of systemic risk. Today, much risk in the financial system is not incurred in the process of extending loans to individuals and non-financial corporations, it is incurred by financial firms betting against one another, and often with huge leverage extended to one another. Of course, it is true that we may lose some liquidity in some lending markets, but this is a cost of better systemic soundness. We can’t demand that banks make conservative loans and then lament that they don’t make more loans. (This applies especially but not only to the public’s and politicians’ attitudes about Fannie and Freddie.)

But, most importantly, worrying about too few smart people in large firms on Wall Street taking too few risks is like worrying about overshooting watering the Sahara desert because it could become a swamp. Yes, in principle, it could happen, but we are so far from an optimal balance – and will likely still be even after criminal penalties–that it’s not an important worry.

We need to find a balance that works for our economy. Right now, we err badly on the side of allowing almost unlimited risk-taking. We need to err on the side of reducing the banking risk incentives too much. Financial services is not where our economy needs the most innovation.

Of course, I have no illusions. Trusting government to do anything right is dangerous. And even if our public servants were all well-intended today, Wall Street will throw so much money at politicians, regulators, lobbyists, and lawyers, that it is extremely unlikely that criminal sanction legislation will ever pass. However, it is a tossup whether we are better off pursuing a tiny probability of passing effective regulation or a modest probability of passing ineffective regulation. Unfortunately, the stakes are high, and we are caught between a rock and a hard place.

Let me close with my opinion of Dodd-Frank and Obama. I congratulate them on their intent. They actually managed to bring financial reform back from the dead, after Wall Street had almost managed to slow the reform process down to a full stop. (Michele Bachmann (R-MN) has already proposed a full repeal of the “job-killing Dodd-Frank financial regulatory bill…” Even the fairly meager Dodd-Frank reform may not last.) Yet, I lament the presence of the actual law. Even though the world is better with Dodd-Frank than without (and especially if I am wrong about my prediction that its specific provisions will be toothless), the real harmful aspect of Dodd-Frank is (a) that it has preempted better legislation to deal with the underlying desire for risk-taking, and (b) that the public now mistakenly believes that the economic system is safer than it was. It is not.

Both comments and trackbacks are currently closed.

5 Comments

  1. Prof Bruce W Bean
    Posted Wednesday, June 8, 2011 at 11:24 am | Permalink

    It is, regrettably, not news that the government is in the hands of lobbyists paid by Wall Street.

    It is not a new charge that Washington is essentially “corrupt.”

    Dodd-Frankenstein is a monument to the power of lobbyists.

    Deferring rule-making from Congress to the regulators simply means more work, and another victory, for lobbyists.

    Gambling on Wall Street is a problem precisely because of the leverage involved. The losses
    are covered by “Other Peoples’ Money.” We have always known this and we have seen it regularly, at least since Long Term Capital Management 13 years ago.

    We did not need 2300 pages of Dodd Frank to deal with this.

    We did not need 650 pages of Carl Levin’s latest Senate report on the Crisis.

    The regulators now have, and have had, the power to impose leverage limits. It is not their meager salaries that keep them from imposing those limits

    But Congress gets involved (having been educated by campaign contributors) and tells the regulators how to do their job.

    Until Congress is cleaned up, and the Washington “system” fundamentally revamped, we shall remain “Prisoners of Wall Street.”

  2. Prof Bruce W Bean
    Posted Wednesday, June 8, 2011 at 11:35 am | Permalink

    Continuing on this theme, please note the following from the NY Times today

    JUNE 8, 2011, 7:19 AM
    Mr. Frank Goes to Wall Street

    By BEN PROTESS
    Representative Barney Frank proved Tuesday night that it never hurts to ask, even when you are asking longtime foes to fork over cash.

    The Massachusetts Democrat held a Wall Street fund-raiser on Tuesday, less than a year after authoring the Dodd-Frank Act, a sweeping crackdown on the financial industry.

    While some bankers saw the event as a striking display of chutzpah, even by Wall Street standards, other industry players were not about to miss the chance to hobnob with one of the nation’s top financial cops.

    JPMorgan Chase, Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley all dispatched officials to the event, hosted by the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, one of Wall Street’s most vocal advocates on the Dodd-Frank financial regulatory law.

    The attendees were a who’s who of Wall Street’s legal and lobbying community. The unusual suspects included Brent Taylor, senior deputy general counsel at UBS.

    Randy Snook, Sifma’s executive vice president, was also seen rushing through the lobby of the group’s lower Manhattan office building. Marti Thomas, a former Goldman Sachs lobbyist, was mentioned at the building’s security desk, though DealBook could not definitively identify her.

    Sifma declined to provide a guest list, and four guards stationed at the desk were diligent gatekeepers of the roster.

    When Mr. Frank arrived, fashionably late, without his trademark glasses and carrying a green gym bag, the guards escorted him to the event.

    The 16-term congressman, who wore a black pinstripe suit with a blue shirt, has long been an unapologetic critic of Wall Street.

    But even Mr. Frank, known for his hard-edged political style and sarcastic wit, has shown a penchant for compromise. He has supported efforts to delay new restrictions on debit card fees, the scorn of bankers big and small. And that was not lost on his audience of donors, some of whom praised Mr. Frank’s recent efforts before entering the fund-raiser.

    Still, banks complain that the Dodd-Frank law threatens to cost the industry several billion dollars.

    And after the fund-raiser on Tuesday, Wall Street’s pockets were sure to be even lighter. “Frank for Congress” was charging $5,000 for a “host,” $2,500 for a “supporter” and $1,000 just to be a “guest.”

    The event was hardly the pugnacious lawmaker’s first attempt to draw from the Wall Street well. In his most recent campaign, which raised roughly $4 million, Mr. Frank received $356,316 from the securities and investment industry, according to the Center for Responsive Politics.

    He is a natural target for donations from bankers and the like. During the crisis, Mr. Frank was chairman of the influential House Financial Services Committee. Now that Congress is in the hands of the Republicans, Mr. Frank is the ranking Democrat on the panel and still wields significant power.

    Mr. Frank says campaign contributions do not influence his policy decisions. The congressman’s spokesman told Marketplace on Tuesday: “If Wall Street is trying to buy influence with him, it has been a dramatic failure.”

    And after representing a liberal district for more than 30 years, a serious Republican challenge to Mr. Frank would seem remote.

    Still, every campaign dollar counts. Mr. Frank made a personal loan to his campaign committee in 2010.

    He won re-election last year by 10 percentage points, a significantly narrower margin of victory that in other recent elections. In past years, Mr. Frank has won by more than 60 percentage points.

  3. Shann Turnbull
    Posted Thursday, June 9, 2011 at 10:00 am | Permalink

    Ivo Welch makes many excellent and insightful points including the inevitability of another crisis. The Secretary General of the Basle Committee has gone on record to agree that another crisis is inevitable.

    But instead of trying to avoid the next crisis, regulators are attempting to accommodate it by increasing the liquidity of bank assets and increasing bank equity. Neither lack of equity nor liquidity was identified as the “key cause of this crisis” by the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission Report. They concluded that it was “dramatic failures of corporate governance and risk management at many systemically important financial institutions.”

    This conclusion is consistent with the view of Ivo Welch that greed was the cause and my prescient concern before the crisis that stock exchanges and regulators were irresponsible – as recorded in this forum on Thursday November 8, 2007 at 12:45 pm at http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/corpgov?s=shann&submit=Go. It is also consistent with the findings of my co-author, Michael Pirson and I in our forthcoming article ‘Corporate Governance, Risk Management, and the Financial Crisis- An Information Processing View’ in Corporate Governance: An international review. Our working paper is at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1723782.

    To control greed we propose that corporate charters introduce a division of powers with checks and balances provided by stakeholders put at risk. This would also constructively and safely connect individuals with knowledge of risks with those with the incentive, power and capability to reduce risks. The result would create what we describe as “Network Governance” that would also connect regulators with management and stakeholders placed at risk.

    However, the next crisis could occur sooner than later. The remedies proposed in our article, like those of Welch could take too long to implement. This might be a blessing in disguise if we now prepare an alternative way of organizing the financial system on a more resilient local self-reliant basis. It is only with a complete breakdown that we are likely to achieve a breakthrough to a new system. In this way we could well overcome the highly influential interests in the existing system as so well articulated by Welch.

    In any event there is an urgent need to establish basis to for a new system to avoid replicating a failed one. As the Governor of the Bank of England noted last October in New York: “Of all the many ways of organising banking, the worst is the one we have today”.

    I have present four non-exclusive proposals for reforming and/or rebuilding the financial system in my paper on “Options for reforming the economy and the banking system” posted at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1322210. Three options are based on depreciating, self-liquidating currencies used so successfully in Europe and the US during the Great Depression described as “Stamp Scrip”. Two options are local issues with one redeemable into official money with the other establishing an independent unit of value determined by renewable energy.

    The third option is for a government issue as described in the Bill introduced into the US Congress in February 1933. The Bill was for the issue of a trillion US dollars is described in the Appendix of the 1933 book by Yale Professor Irving Fishers that can be downloaded from http://userpage.fu-berlin.de/~roehrigw/fisher/ . The sale of stamps by the US Post Office would allow it to raise sufficient funds to redeem all the issue in 12 month and make a $40 Billion Gross Profit. The Federal Reserve was not involved and probable for this reason it did not proceed with the New Deal announced two weeks later.

    Today, the use of stamps can be avoided by using cell phones that can store units of value and remit the usage fee used to depreciate the money. Billions of cell phones are being used in this way in the developing world that have few land lines for phones and even fewer banks. Cell phones used as electronic purses allow the banking system to be completely by-passed.

    Cell phone technology could thus in any event create an alternative decentralized, self-reliant and resilient financial systems as outlined in my article published last year by the Journal of Financial Transformation ‘How might cell phone money change the financial system? Posted at http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract_id=1602323.

  4. Pete Gazda
    Posted Tuesday, June 28, 2011 at 2:51 am | Permalink

    The financial crisis is not solely on the shoulders of Wall Street. Businesses are slowly being over-run by foreign interest in multiple industries. Surveys and studies are not needed to observe small businesses being owned and operated by undocumented or minority groups with connections overseas.

    The government has allowed tax incentives to promote such businesses with little to no restrictions on business operations or accounting. While Wall Street is in the spot light, these small businesses are operating below the radar.

    Years ago businesses followed a hierarchy of manufacturer, importer, distributor, dealer and the end consumer. Each segment would profit at each link in the chain.

    There has been an increase of foreign businesses opening in the United States that are removing the links in the chain. They are selling direct to the consumer with the majority of US money being sent overseas.

    Businesses owned by US citizens cannot compete with foreign companies that operate within the US Borders. We look at Wall Street as the thief coming through the front door while we are being robbed through the backdoor. At the same time corporations on Wall Street fail to recognize the threat as well. Success is measured on increasing profits margins with companies trying to trim costs. They associate their problems as an internal issue but lose sight of the big picture and the exportation of our economy.

    Preventing the next financial crisis will only be averted if we exam bottom-up economics and not place the microscope solely on Wall Street.

  5. Prof. A. Joseph Warburton
    Posted Saturday, July 16, 2011 at 8:45 pm | Permalink

    Ivo Welch recommends using fiduciary responsibilities to curtail risk taking by managers of financial institutions. But would a strengthening of fiduciary responsibilities really have any effects?

    In a recent study, I find empirical evidence suggesting that stronger fiduciary duties are indeed associated with a reduction in risk taking. And that is not all. The evidence also suggests that stronger fiduciary duties are effective in curtailing managerial compensation.

    My study, “Trusts Versus Corporations: An Empirical Analysis of Competing Organizational Forms,” 36 Journal of Corporation Law 183 (2010), exploits variation generated by a change in British regulations in the 1990s that allowed mutual funds to organize as either a trust or a corporation. Trust law imposes stricter fiduciary responsibilities on managers than corporate law does. I find that the trust managers charge significantly lower fees than their observationally equivalent corporate counterparts. Trust managers also choose portfolios with lower risk. However, trust managers underperform their corporate counterparts, even after differences in risk are accommodated. The results suggest that heightened fiduciary duties can mitigate managerial risk-taking and agency conflict, but at the cost of lower risk-adjusted performance.

    Hence, Ivo Welsh may not have to resort to the criminal penalties he outlines, as fiduciary responsibilities may produce the desired outcome – so long as one can tolerate a financial services industry that generates lowers performance and potentially less innovation.

    The paper is available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1290722.

3 Trackbacks

  1. […] Preventing the Next Financial Crisis – via HLS – We have weathered the worst of the financial crisis of 2008-9. Time for renewed optimism? Unfortunately not. The next financial crisis is already programmed. It’s somewhat like an earthquake in Southern California. We cannot predict exactly when it will happen, but we know that it will. Yet unlike earthquakes, financial crises are man-made. They need not happen. They happen because we allow them to happen. We could take many measures to reduce their frequency and depths, but we fail to do so. […]

  2. […] It is very much assumed that “the root of the problem is everyone on Wall Street has the “incentive to gamble” regardless of society’s interests […]

  3. […] It is very much assumed that “the root of the problem is everyone on Wall Street has the “incentive to gamble” regardless of society’s interests […]