Robert Merton is Professor of Finance at the MIT Sloan School of Management and Richard T. Thakor is Assistant Professor of Finance at the University of Minnesota Carlson School of Management. This post is based on their recent paper, forthcoming in the Journal of Banking and Finance.
The existing Chapter 11 bankruptcy process is time-consuming and financially costly for firms, which causes many firms that file for bankruptcy to eventually liquidate due to the value dissipation during bankruptcy (see, e.g., Morrison (2007) and Hotchkiss et al. (2008)). This leads to significant social and private costs, and reduces the documented tax-shield and agency-cost-reduction benefits of corporate leverage. In No-fault Default, Chapter 11 Bankruptcy, and Financial Institutions, we propose and theoretically analyze the idea of a “no-fault-default” structure for corporate debt, which facilitates harvesting the benefits of leverage without the associated deadweight costs of bankruptcy.
The main idea of no-fault-default debt is to enable the firm to transform its debt claims into equity claims upon default on the debt, thus allowing a reallocation of control rights to bondholders with minimal disruption of the business operations of the firm. Put differently, when a bondholder demands payment at maturity, the company can choose to make the payment or surrender equity in the company. If the company does not have enough funds to make the promised payment to the bondholders, the bond converts automatically into equity—a transaction not requiring bankruptcy—and the firm also issues new debt with a longer maturity in exchange for the old debt. If the current shareholders wish to maintain corporate control, then they would need only to put up additional cash needed to buy the new equity. As with normal debt, other features like covenant restrictions—such as provisions which trigger early payment to the bondholders—can be included. We also show that no-fault-default debt remains feasible, with some modifications (such as adding a conversion option) even in the presence of well-known frictions like risk-shifting moral hazard.